Alman tarihçi okulu'nun Joseph Alois Schumpeter üzerine etkisi

Bu çalışmanın temel amacı Alman Tarihçi Okulu’nun 20. yüzyılın en önemli iktisatçılardan biri olanJoseph Alois Schumpeter üzerindeki etkisini ortaya koymaktır. Schumpeter’in fikirsel olarak geliştiği ilkzaman dilimi başta Schmoller ve Weber olmak üzere Alman Tarihçi Okulu temsilcilerinin Klasik Okulu’nuntemel fikirlerine karşı savaş açtığı dönemlere denk gelmektedir. Alman Tarihçi Okulu bu bağlamda ilk olarakklasik öğretinin tümdengelimci yöntemini reddederek tarihsel yönteme dayalı tümevarımcı bir yöntemisavunmuştur. Bu bağlamda Schumpeter’in tarih ve iktisat sosyolojisine dayalı çok yönlü metodolojisi bugelişmenin bir sonucu olarak görülebilir. Gerek Alman Tarihçi Okulu’nun gerekse Schumpeter’in önemliçalışma alanlarından biri hiç şüphesiz girişimci ve onun rolüne yönelik olmuştur. Alman Tarihçi Okulu’namensup iktisatçılar ve sosyologlar kapitalist toplumlarda girişimciliğin kökeni ve onun sosyal ve ekonomikdeğişim üzerindeki etkisi konusunda fikirler ileri sürdüler. Aşağıda girişimciyi dinamizmin ve değişiminkaynağı olarak gören Alman Tarihçi Okulu’nun bu bağlamda Schumpeter üzerindeki etkisi de ortayakoymaya çalışılacaktır.

The influence of the German historical school on Joseph Alois Schumpeter

The main purpose of this study is to determine the influence of the German Historical School onJoseph Alois Schumpeter, one of the most important economists of the 20thcentury. Schumpeter’s earlyideological development coincides with the “declaration of war” to the basic ideas of the Classical School byrepresentatives of the German Historical School led by Schmoller and Weber. In this context, the GermanHistorical School rejected the deductive methods of classical teaching and advocated inductive reasoningbased on the historical method. In this record, Schumpeter’s versatile methodology leaning against historyand economical sociology can be regarded as a result of this development. Without a shadow of doubt, one ofthe most important fields of study of both the German Historical School and Schumpeter addresses theentrepreneur and his role. Economists and sociologists representing the German Historical School proposedideas on the origins of entrepreneurship in capitalist societies and its impact on social and economic change.The purpose of the text below is to address the related influence of the German Historical School, whichregards the entrepreneur as the source of dynamism and change, on Schumpeter.

___

  • Allen, Robert Loring (1991), Opening Doors: The Life and Work of Joseph Schumpeter, Vol.1 (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers).
  • Andersen, Esben Sloth (1991), “Schumpeter’s Vienna and The Schools of Thought: A Report From a Study on Schumpeter and The Analysis of Economic Evolution,” (http://www.business.aau.dk/evolution/esapapers/esa90-93/WP70.pdf), Erişim Tarihi: 25.12.2009.
  • Arena, Richard vePaul Marie Romani (2002), “Schumpeter on Entrepreneurship,” Arena, Richard ve Cecile Dangel-Hagnauer (eds.), The Contribution of Joseph A.Schumpeter to Economics (London- NY: Routledge): 167-183.
  • Arena, Richard (2006), “On The Relation between Economics and Sociology: Marshall and Schumpeter,” (http://www.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/service/tenji/amjas/Arena.pdf), Erişim Tarihi: 10.11.2009.
  • Bertocco, Giancarlo (2008), “Finance and Development: Is Schumpeter’s Analysis Still Relevant?,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 32: 1161-1175.
  • Boldrin, Michele (2009), “Growth and Cycles, in the Mode of Marx and Schumpeter,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 56/4: 415-442.
  • Brouwer, Maria T. (2002), “Weber, Schumpeter and Knight on Entrepreneurship and Economic Development,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12/1: 83-105.
  • Ebner, Alexander (2000), “Schumpeter and the “Schmollerprogramm”: Integrating Theory and History in the Analysis of Economic Development,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics,10/3: 355-372.
  • Ebner, Alexander (2003), “The Institutional Analysis of Entrepreneurship: Historist Aspects of Schumpeter's Development Theory,” Backhaus, Jürgen G. (ed.), Joseph Alois Schumpeter: Entrepreneurship, Style and Vision (Boston:Kluwer Academic Publishers): 117-139.
  • Ebner, Alexander (2005), “Entrepreneurship and Economic Development: From Classical Political Economy to Economic Sociology,” Journal of Economic Studies, 32/3: 256-274.
  • Ebner, Alexander (2006), “Institutions, Entrepreneurship, and the Rationale of Government: An Outline of the Schumpeterian Theory of the State,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 59: 497-515.
  • Economakis, George E. ve John Millios (2001), “Historical School, German,” Encyclopedia of International Political Economy, Vol. II (London, New York: Routledge): 686-687.
  • Freeman, Christopher ve Francisco Louça (2001), As Time Goes By: From the Industrial Revolutions to the Information Revolution (NY: Oxford University Press Inc.).
  • Godin, Benoit (2008), “In the Shadow of Schumpeter: W. Rupert Maclaurin and the Study of Technological Innovation,” Minerva, 46:343-360.
  • Haberler, Gottfried (1950), “Joseph Alois Schumpeter 1883-1950,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64/3: 333-372.
  • Haller, Markus (2004), “Mixing Economics and Ethics: Carl Menger vs Gustav Von Schmoller,” Social Science Information, 43/1: 5-33.
  • Hebert, Robert F. ve Albert N. Link (2006), “The Entrepreneur as Innovator,” Journal of Technology Transfer, 31/5: 589-597.
  • Hebert, Robert F. ve Albert N. Link (1982), The Entrepreneur: Mainstream Views and Radical Critiques (New York: Praeger. Publishers).
  • Henrekson, Magnus ve Jakobsson Ulf (2001), “Where Schumpeter was Nearly Right- The Swedish Model and Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11: 331-358.
  • Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2008), “Review Essay: Prospects for Economic Sociology,” Philosophy of the Social Sciences, 38/1: 133-149.
  • Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2001), How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science (NY: Roudledge).
  • Hulten, Staffan (2005), “Historical School and Institutionalism,” Journal of Economic Studies, 32/2: 169-178.
  • Ikeda, Yukihiro (2008), “The German Historical School: Toward the Integration of the Social Sciences,” The History of Economic Thought, 50/1: 79-95.
  • Kurz, Heinz D. (2007), “Ricardian Vice,” William A. Darity (ed.) International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences (New York: MacMillan Reference Library, 2nd Ed.): 241-243.
  • Legris, Andre (2001), “On the Boundaries between Economic Analysis and Economic Sociology,” ARENA, Richard ve Cecile Dangel-Hagnauer (ed.), The Contribution of Joseph A. Schumpeter to Economics (London/NY: Routledge): 89-105.
  • Macdonald, Ronan (1965), “Schumpeter and Max Weber- Central Visions and Social Theories,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79/3: 373-396.
  • Machlup, Fritz (1951), “Schumpeter's Economic Methodology,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 33/2: 145-151.
  • McCraw, Thomas K. (2007), Prophet of Innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and Creative Destruction (Cambridge: Harvard University Press).
  • Michaelides, Panayotis G. ve John G. Millios (2009), “Joseph Schumpeter and the German Historical School,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33/3: 495-516.
  • Michaelides, Panayotis G. ve John. G. Millios (2005), “Did Hilferding Influence Schumpeter?,” History of Economics Review, 41: 98-125.
  • Milimov, Allex (1994), “Joseph A.Schumpeter: His Life and Work,” History of Economics Review, 22: 119-123.
  • Pickhardt, Michael (2005), “Some Remarks on Self-interest, the Historical Schools and the Evolution of the Theory of Public Goods,” Journal of Economic Studies, 32/3: 275- 293.
  • Reinert, Erik S. (2002), “Schumpeter in the Context of Two Canons of Economic Thought,” Industry and Innovation, 6/1: 23-39.
  • Rosenberg, Nathan (2000), Schumpeter and the Endogeneity of Technology: Some American Perspectives (London/New York: Routledge).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1928), “The Instability of Capitalism,” The Economic Journal, 38/151: 361-386.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1939), Business Cycless: A Theoretical,Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process, Vol:I (New York and London: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc.).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (New York: Harper and Brothers).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1947), “The Creative Response in Economic History,” The Journal of Economic History, 7/2: 149-159.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1949), “The Communist Manifesto in Sociology and Economics,” Journal of Political Economy, 57/3: 199-212.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954) History of Economic Analysis (London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954b), Economic Doctrine and Method: An Historical Sketch (NY: Oxford University Press) (Translated by R. Aris).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1966), Imperialism and Social Classes (Cleveland and New York: Meridian Books, 9th Ed) (Translated by Heinz Norden).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1978), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle (New York, Oxford University Press).
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. ve Yasuma Takata (1998), Power or Pure Economics ? (New York: MacMillan Press).
  • Screpanti, Ernesto ve Stefano Zamagni (2005), An Outline of the History of Economic Thought (New York: Oxford University Press, 2nd Ed.).
  • Senn, Peter R. (2005), “The German Historical Schools in the History of Economic Thought,” Journal of Economic Studies, 32/3: 185-255
  • Shionaya, Yuichi (1997), “A Methodological Appraisal of Schmoller’s Research Program,” Koslowski, Peter (Ed.), The Theory of Ethical Economy in The Historical School (Berlin: Springer): 57-78.
  • Shionaya, Yuichi (1997), Schumpeter and the Idea of Social Science: A Metatheoretical Study (New York: Cambridge University Press).
  • Shionaya,Yuichi (2001a), “Introduction”, Shionaya, Yuichi (ed.), The German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics (New York: Routledge): 1-6.
  • Shionaya, Yuichi (2001b), “Joseph Schumppeter on the Relationship between Economics and Sociology from the Perspective of Doctrinal History,” Shionaya, Yuichi (Ed.), The German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics (New York: Routledge): 138-154.
  • Shionaya, Yuichi (2001c), “Rational Reconstruction of the German Historical School: An Overview,” Shionaya, Yuichi (ed.), German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics (New York: Routledge): 7-18.
  • Shionaya, Yuichi (2005), The Soul of the German Historical School ( New York: Springer).
  • Silveira, Antonio M. (1997), “Senior, Wagner and Schmoller: Indetermination and Social Policy Conclusions,” Backhaus, Jurgen G. (Ed.), Essays on Social Security and Taxation: Gustav von Schmoller and Adolph Wagner Reconsidered (Marburg: Metropolis- Verlag): 361-86.
  • Swedberg, Richard (1989), “Joseph A. Schumpeter and the Tradition of Economic Sociology,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145/3: 508-524.
  • Swedberg, Richard (1991a), Joseph A. Schumpeter: His Life and Work (Princeton: Princeton University Press).
  • Swedberg, Richard (1991b), “Introduction: The Man and His Work,” Swedberg, Richard (ed.), Joseph A.Schumpeter: The Economics and Sociology of Capitalism (Princeton: Princeton University Press): 3-98.
  • Tamura, Shin’ichi (2000), “Gustav von Schmoller and Werner Sombart: A Contrast in the Historico-Ethical Method and Social Policy,” Shionoya, Yeuichi (ed.), German Historical School : The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics (London and New York: Routledge): 105-119 .
  • Wadhwani, R. Daniel ve Geoffrey Jones (2001), “Schumpeter’s Plea: Historical Approaches to Entrepreneurship Research,” (http://sociology.unc.edu/colloqseries/wadhwani), Erişim Tarihi: 20.12.2009.
  • Weber, Max (1930), The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons)